The price would be Po and the quantity would be Qo o for original. Graphically, the equilibrium would look as follows:. Now suppose the government begins subsidizing sellers by paying them Z dollars per unit sold.
They sell until:. This reduction from equilibrium quantity is what causes a deadweight loss in the market since there are consumers and producers who are no longer able to buy and supply the good. Due to the increase in price, many consumers will switch away from oil to alternative options.
This decrease in quantity demand of 1. It is no coincidence that the size of the decrease is the same. When you create the wedge between consumers and producers, you are finding the quantity where the full amount of the tax is incurred but the market is still at equilibrium.
Remember that quantity demanded must equal quantity supplied or the market will not be stable. This mirrored decrease in quantity ensures this is still the case. Again, this is due to elasticity, or the relative responsiveness to the price chance, which will be explored in more detail shortly.
While a tax drives a wedge that increases the price consumers have to pay and decreases the price producers receive, a subsidy does the opposite. A subsidy is a benefit given by the government to groups or individuals, usually in the form of a cash payment or a tax reduction. A subsidy is often given to remove some type of burden, and it is often considered to be in the overall interest of the public.
In economic terms, a subsidy drives a wedge, decreasing the price consumers pay and increasing the price producers receive, with the government incurring an expense. In response, the government has enacted many policies to allow low-income families to still become homeowners. Note the following policy is unrealistic but allows for easy comprehension of the effect of subsidies. With all government policies we have examined so far, we have wanted to determine whether the result of the policy increases or decreases market surplus.
With a subsidy, we want to do the same analysis. Unfortunately, because increases in surplus overlap on our diagram, it becomes more complicated. To simplify the analysis, the following diagram separates the changes to producers, consumers, and government onto different graphs. This increases producer surplus by areas A and B. This increases consumer surplus by areas C and D.
To summarize:. Areas A, B, C and D are transferred from the government to consumers and producers. There are two things to notice about this example. First, the policy was successful at increasing quantity from 40, homes to 60, homes. Second, it resulted in a deadweight loss because equilibrium quantity was too high. Remember, anytime quantity is changed from the equilibrium quantity, in the absence of externalities, there is a deadweight loss.
This is true for when quantity is decreased and when it is increased. Taxes and subsidies are more complicated than a price or quantity control as they involve a third economic player: the government. As we saw, who the tax or subsidy is levied on is irrelevant when looking at how the market ends up. Note that the last three sections have painted a fairly grim picture about policy instruments. This is because our model currently does not include the external costs economic players impose to the macro-environment pollution, disease, etc.
Revenue that a government collects from a tax is counted as a positive surplus, so it follows that costs that a government pays out via a subsidy are counted as negative surplus. Because total surplus in a market is lower under a subsidy than in a free market, the conclusion is that subsidies create economic inefficiency, known as deadweight loss. The deadweight loss in this diagram is given by area H, the shaded triangle to the right of the free market quantity. Economic inefficiency is created by a subsidy because it costs a government more to enact a subsidy than the subsidy creates additional benefits to consumers and producers.
Despite the apparent inefficiency of subsidies, it isn't necessarily true that subsidies are bad policy. For example, subsidies can raise rather than lower total surplus when positive externalities are present in a market. Also, subsidies sometimes make sense when considering fairness or equity issues or when considering markets for necessities such as food or clothing where the limitation on willingness to pay is affordability rather than product attractiveness.
Nevertheless, the preceding analysis is vital to a thoughtful analysis of subsidy policy, since it highlights the fact that subsidies lower rather than raise the value created for society by well-functioning markets.
Actively scan device characteristics for identification. Use precise geolocation data. Select personalised content. Create a personalised content profile. Measure ad performance. Select basic ads. Create a personalised ads profile. Select personalised ads.
Apply market research to generate audience insights. Measure content performance. Develop and improve products. List of Partners vendors. Share Flipboard Email.
Social Sciences Economics U. Jodi Beggs. Economics Expert.
0コメント